How should Obama reform health care?

.
Click here to also view the article of the same title in The New Yorker of January 26th.

In addition, please read "Sick - The Untold Story of America's Health Care and the People Who Pay the Price" (Harper Collins 2007) by Jonathan Cohn, a Senior Editor at The New Republic (available from your local library or Amazon.com for $7.99 + shipping).

Please also see the voluminous material posted on this bulletin board for our August 2007 meeting 18 months ago.
Post Reply
UtahOwl
Site Admin
Posts: 82
Joined: Mon Jul 28, 2008 10:48 pm

How should Obama reform health care?

Post by UtahOwl »

Proposed Topic = How should Obama reform health care?

(Editorial Note – There is a wealth of information on this bulletin board from the last time we discussed national health care in August 2007 – 18 months ago.)

Suggested Reading = the following article from The New Yorker of 26 January 2009.

Getting There from Here: How should Obama reform health care?
by Atul Gawande

Our jerry-rigged health-care system contains many models that reformers can build on.

In every industrialized nation, the movement to reform health care has begun with stories about cruelty. The Canadians had stories like the 1946 Toronto Globe and Mail report of a woman in labor who was refused help by three successive physicians, apparently because of her inability to pay. In Australia, a 1954 letter published in the Sydney Morning Herald sought help for a young woman who had lung disease. She couldn't afford to refill her oxygen tank, and had been forced to ration her intake "to a point where she is on the borderline of death." In Britain, George Bernard Shaw was at a London hospital visiting an eminent physician when an assistant came in to report that a sick man had arrived requesting treatment. "Is he worth it?" the physician asked. It was the normality of the question that shocked Shaw and prompted his scathing and influential 1906 play, "The Doctor's Dilemma." The British health system, he charged, was "a conspiracy to exploit popular credulity and human suffering."

In the United States, our stories are like the one that appeared in the Times before Christmas. Starla Darling, pregnant and due for delivery, had just taken maternity leave from her factory job at Archway & Mother's Cookie Company, in Ashland, Ohio, when she received a letter informing her that the company was going out of business. In three days, the letter said, she and almost three hundred co-workers would be laid off, and would lose their health-insurance coverage. The company was self-insured, so the employees didn't have the option of paying for the insurance themselves-their insurance plan was being terminated.

"When I heard that I was losing my insurance, I was scared," Darling told the Times. Her husband had been laid off from his job, too. "I remember that the bill for my son's delivery in 2005 was about $9,000, and I knew I would never be able to pay that by myself." So she prevailed on her midwife to induce labor while she still had insurance coverage. During labor, Darling began bleeding profusely, and needed a Cesarean section. Mother and baby pulled through. But the insurer denied Darling's claim for coverage. The couple ended up owing more than seventeen thousand dollars.

The stories become unconscionable in any society that purports to serve the needs of ordinary people, and, at some alchemical point, they combine with opportunity and leadership to produce change. Britain reached this point and enacted universal health-care coverage in 1945, Canada in 1966, Australia in 1974. The United States may finally be there now. In 2007, fifty-seven million Americans had difficulty paying their medical bills, up fourteen million from 2003. On average, they had two thousand dollars in medical debt and had been contacted by a collection agency at least once. Because, in part, of underpayment, half of American hospitals operated at a loss in 2007. Today, large numbers of employers are limiting or dropping insurance coverage in order to stay afloat, or simply going under-even hospitals themselves.

Yet wherever the prospect of universal health insurance has been considered, it has been widely attacked as a Bolshevik fantasy-a coercive system to be imposed upon people by benighted socialist master planners. People fear the unintended consequences of drastic change, the blunt force of government. However terrible the system may seem, we all know that it could be worse-especially for those who already have dependable coverage and access to good doctors and hospitals.

Many would-be reformers hold that "true" reform must simply override those fears. They believe that a new system will be far better for most people, and that those who would hang on to the old do so out of either lack of imagination or narrow self-interest. On the left, then, single-payer enthusiasts argue that the only coherent solution is to end private health insurance and replace it with a national insurance program. And, on the right, the free marketeers argue that the only coherent solution is to end public insurance and employer-controlled health benefits so that we can all buy our own coverage and put market forces to work.

Neither side can stand the other. But both reserve special contempt for the pragmatists, who would build around the mess we have. The country has this one chance, the idealist maintains, to sweep away our inhumane, wasteful patchwork system and replace it with something new and more rational. So we should prepare for a bold overhaul, just as every other Western democracy has. True reform requires transformation at a stroke. But is this really the way it has occurred in other countries? The answer is no. And the reality of how health reform has come about elsewhere is both surprising and instructive.

No example is more striking than that of Great Britain, which has the most socialized health system in the industrialized world. Established on July 5, 1948, the National Health Service owns the vast majority of the country's hospitals, blood banks, and ambulance operations, employs most specialist physicians as salaried government workers, and has made medical care available to every resident for free. The system is so thoroughly government-controlled that, across the Atlantic, we imagine it had to have been imposed by fiat, by the coercion of ideological planners bending the system to their will.

But look at the news report in the Times of London on July 6, 1948, headlined "FIRST DAY OF HEALTH SERVICE." You might expect descriptions of bureaucratic shock troops walking into hospitals, insurance-company executives and doctors protesting in the streets, patients standing outside chemist shops worrying about whether they can get their prescriptions filled. Instead, there was only a four-paragraph notice between an item on the King and Queen's return from a holiday in Scotland and one on currency problems in Germany.

The beginning of the new national health service "was taking place smoothly," the report said. No major problems were noted by the 2,751 hospitals involved or by patients arriving to see their family doctors. Ninety per cent of the British Medical Association's members signed up with the program voluntarily-and found that they had a larger and steadier income by doing so. The greatest difficulty, it turned out, was the unexpected pent-up demand for everything from basic dental care to pediatric visits for hundreds of thousands of people who had been going without.

The program proved successful and lasting, historians say, precisely because it was not the result of an ideologue's master plan. Instead, the N.H.S. was a pragmatic outgrowth of circumstances peculiar to Britain immediately after the Second World War. The single most important moment that determined what Britain's health-care system would look like was not any policymaker's meeting in 1945 but the country's declaration of war on Germany, on September 3, 1939.

As tensions between the two countries mounted, Britain's ministers realized that they would have to prepare not only for land and sea combat but also for air attacks on cities on an unprecedented scale. And so, in the days before war was declared, the British government oversaw an immense evacuation; three and a half million people moved out of the cities and into the countryside. The government had to arrange transport and lodging for those in need, along with supervision, food, and schooling for hundreds of thousands of children whose parents had stayed behind to join in the war effort. It also had to insure that medical services were in place-both in the receiving regions, whose populations had exploded, and in the cities, where up to two million war-injured civilians and returning servicemen were anticipated.

As a matter of wartime necessity, the government began a national Emergency Medical Service to supplement the local services. Within a period of months, sometimes weeks, it built or expanded hundreds of hospitals. It conducted a survey of the existing hospitals and discovered that essential services were either missing or severely inadequate-laboratories, X-ray facilities, ambulances, care for fractures and burns and head injuries. The Ministry of Health was forced to upgrade and, ultimately, to operate these services itself.

The war compelled the government to provide free hospital treatment for civilian casualties, as well as for combatants. In London and other cities, the government asked local hospitals to transfer some of the sick to private hospitals in the outer suburbs in order to make room for victims of the war. As a result, the government wound up paying for a large fraction of the private hospitals' costs. Likewise, doctors received government salaries for the portion of their time that was devoted to the new wartime medical service. When the Blitz came, in September, 1940, vast numbers of private hospitals and clinics were destroyed, further increasing the government's share of medical costs. The private hospitals and doctors whose doors were still open had far fewer paying patients and were close to financial ruin.

Churchill's government intended the program to be temporary. But the war destroyed the status quo for patients, doctors, and hospitals alike. Moreover, the new system proved better than the old. Despite the ravages of war, the health of the population had improved. The medical and social services had reduced infant and adult mortality rates. Even the dental care was better. By the end of 1944, when the wartime medical service began to demobilize, the country's citizens did not want to see it go. The private hospitals didn't, either; they had come to depend on those government payments.

By 1945, when the National Health Service was proposed, it had become evident that a national system of health coverage was not only necessary but also largely already in place-with nationally run hospitals, salaried doctors, and free care for everyone. So, while the ideal of universal coverage was spurred by those horror stories, the particular system that emerged in Britain was not the product of socialist ideology or a deliberate policy process in which all the theoretical options were weighed. It was, instead, an almost conservative creation: a program that built on a tested, practical means of providing adequate health care for everyone, while protecting the existing services that people depended upon every day. No other major country has adopted the British system-not because it didn't work but because other countries came to universalize health care under entirely different circumstances.

In France, in the winter of 1945, President de Gaulle was likewise weighing how to insure that his nation's population had decent health care after the devastation of war. But the system that he inherited upon liberation had no significant public insurance or hospital sector. Seventy-five per cent of the population paid cash for private medical care, and many people had become too destitute to afford heat, let alone medications or hospital visits.

Long before the war, large manufacturers and unions had organized collective insurance funds for their employees, financed through a self-imposed payroll tax, rather than a set premium. This was virtually the only insurance system in place, and it became the scaffolding for French health care. With an almost impossible range of crises on its hands-food shortages, destroyed power plants, a quarter of the population living as refugees-the de Gaulle government had neither the time nor the capacity to create an entirely new health-care system. So it built on what it had, expanding the existing payroll-tax-funded, private insurance system to cover all wage earners, their families, and retirees. The self-employed were added in the nineteen-sixties. And the remainder of uninsured residents were finally included in 2000.

Today, Sécurité Sociale provides payroll-tax-financed insurance to all French residents, primarily through a hundred and forty-four independent, not-for-profit, local insurance funds. The French health-care system has among the highest public-satisfaction levels of any major Western country; and, compared with Americans, the French have a higher life expectancy, lower infant mortality, more physicians, and lower costs. In 2000, the World Health Organization ranked it the best health-care system in the world. (The United States was ranked thirty-seventh.)

Switzerland, because of its wartime neutrality, escaped the damage that drove health-care reform elsewhere. Instead, most of its citizens came to rely on private commercial health-insurance coverage. When problems with coverage gaps and inconsistencies finally led the nation to pass its universal-coverage law, in 1994, it had no experience with public insurance. So the country-you get the picture now-built on what it already had. It required every resident to purchase private health insurance and provided subsidies to limit the cost to no more than about ten per cent of an individual's income.

Every industrialized nation in the world except the United States has a national system that guarantees affordable health care for all its citizens. Nearly all have been popular and successful. But each has taken a drastically different form, and the reason has rarely been ideology. Rather, each country has built on its own history, however imperfect, unusual, and untidy.

Social scientists have a name for this pattern of evolution based on past experience. They call it "path-dependence." In the battles between Betamax and VHS video recorders, Mac and P.C. computers, the QWERTY typewriter keyboard and alternative designs, they found that small, early events played a far more critical role in the market outcome than did the question of which design was better. Paul Krugman received a Nobel Prize in Economics in part for showing that trade patterns and the geographic location of industrial production are also path-dependent. The first firms to get established in a given industry, he pointed out, attract suppliers, skilled labor, specialized financing, and physical infrastructure. This entrenches local advantages that lead other firms producing similar goods to set up business in the same area-even if prices, taxes, and competition are stiffer. "The long shadow cast by history over location is apparent at all scales, from the smallest to the largest-from the cluster of costume jewelry firms in Providence to the concentration of 60 million people in the Northeast Corridor," Krugman wrote in 1991.

With path-dependent processes, the outcome is unpredictable at the start. Small, often random events early in the process are "remembered," continuing to have influence later. And, as you go along, the range of future possibilities gets narrower. It becomes more and more unlikely that you can simply shift from one path to another, even if you are locked in on a path that has a lower payoff than an alternate one.

The political scientist Paul Pierson observed that this sounds a lot like politics, and not just economics. When a social policy entails major setup costs and large numbers of people who must devote time and resources to developing expertise, early choices become difficult to reverse. And if the choices involve what economists call "increasing returns"-where the benefits of a policy increase as more people organize their activities around it-those early decisions become self-reinforcing. America's transportation system developed this way. The century-old decision to base it on gasoline-powered automobiles led to a gigantic manufacturing capacity, along with roads, repair facilities, and fuelling stations that now make it exceedingly difficult to do things differently.

There's a similar explanation for our employment-based health-care system. Like Switzerland, America made it through the war without damage to its domestic infrastructure. Unlike Switzerland, we sent much of our workforce abroad to fight. This led the Roosevelt Administration to impose national wage controls to prevent inflationary increases in labor costs. Employers who wanted to compete for workers could, however, offer commercial health insurance. That spurred our distinctive reliance on private insurance obtained through one's place of employment-a source of troubles (for employers and the unemployed alike) that we've struggled with for six decades.

Some people regard the path-dependence of our policies as evidence of weak leadership; we have, they charge, allowed our choices to be constrained by history and by vested interests. But that's too simple. The reality is that leaders are held responsible for the hazards of change as well as for the benefits. And the history of master-planned transformation isn't exactly inspiring. The familiar horror story is Mao's Great Leap Forward, where the collectivization of farming caused some thirty million deaths from famine. But, to take an example from our own era, consider Defense Secretary Donald Rumsfeld's disastrous reinvention of modern military operations for the 2003 invasion of Iraq, in which he insisted on deploying far fewer ground troops than were needed. Or consider a health-care example: the 2003 prescription-drug program for America's elderly.

This legislation aimed to expand the Medicare insurance program in order to provide drug coverage for some ten million elderly Americans who lacked it, averaging fifteen hundred dollars per person annually. The White House, congressional Republicans, and the pharmaceutical industry opposed providing this coverage through the existing Medicare public-insurance program. Instead, they created an entirely new, market-oriented program that offered the elderly an online choice of competing, partially subsidized commercial drug-insurance plans. It was, in theory, a reasonable approach. But it meant that twenty-five million Americans got new drug plans, and that all sixty thousand retail pharmacies in the United States had to establish contracts and billing systems for those plans.

On January 1, 2006, the program went into effect nationwide. The result was chaos. There had been little realistic consideration of how millions of elderly people with cognitive difficulties, chronic illness, or limited English would manage to select the right plan for themselves. Even the savviest struggled to figure out how to navigate the choices: insurance companies offered 1,429 prescription-drug plans across the country. People arrived at their pharmacy only to discover that they needed an insurance card that hadn't come, or that they hadn't received pre-authorization for their drugs, or had switched to a plan that didn't cover the drugs they took. Tens of thousands were unable to get their prescriptions filled, many for essential drugs like insulin, inhalers, and blood-pressure medications. The result was a public-health crisis in thirty-seven states, which had to provide emergency pharmacy payments for the frail. We will never know how many were harmed, but it is likely that the program killed people.

This is the trouble with the lure of the ideal. Over and over in the health-reform debate, one hears serious policy analysts say that the only genuine solution is to replace our health-care system (with a single-payer system, a free-market system, or whatever); anything else is a missed opportunity. But this is a siren song.

Yes, American health care is an appallingly patched-together ship, with rotting timbers, water leaking in, mercenaries on board, and fifteen per cent of the passengers thrown over the rails just to keep it afloat. But hundreds of millions of people depend on it. The system provides more than thirty-five million hospital stays a year, sixty-four million surgical procedures, nine hundred million office visits, three and a half billion prescriptions. It represents a sixth of our economy. There is no dry-docking health care for a few months, or even for an afternoon, while we rebuild it. Grand plans admit no possibility of mistakes or failures, or the chance to learn from them. If we get things wrong, people will die. This doesn't mean that ambitious reform is beyond us. But we have to start with what we have.

That kind of constraint isn't unique to the health-care system. A century ago, the modern phone system was built on a structure that came to be called the P.S.T.N., the Public Switched Telephone Network. This automated system connects our phone calls twenty-four hours a day, and over time it has had to be upgraded. But you can't turn off the phone system and do a reboot. It's too critical to too many. So engineers have had to add on one patch after another.

The P.S.T.N. is probably the shaggiest, most convoluted system around; it contains tens of millions of lines of software code. Given a chance for a do-over, no self-respecting engineer would create anything remotely like it. Yet this jerry-rigged system has provided us with 911 emergency service, voice mail, instant global connectivity, mobile-phone lines, and the transformation from analog to digital communication. It has also been fantastically reliable, designed to have as little as two hours of total downtime every forty years. As a system that can't be turned off, the P.S.T.N. may be the ultimate in path-dependence. But that hasn't prevented dramatic change. The structure may not have undergone revolution; the way it functions has. The P.S.T.N. has made the twenty-first century possible.

So accepting the path-dependent nature of our health-care system-recognizing that we had better build on what we've got-doesn't mean that we have to curtail our ambitions. The overarching goal of health-care reform is to establish a system that has three basic attributes. It should leave no one uncovered-medical debt must disappear as a cause of personal bankruptcy in America. It should no longer be an economic catastrophe for employers. And it should hold doctors, nurses, hospitals, drug and device companies, and insurers collectively responsible for making care better, safer, and less costly.

We cannot swap out our old system for a new one that will accomplish all this. But we can build a new system on the old one. On the start date for our new health-care system-on, say, January 1, 2011-there need be no noticeable change for the vast majority of Americans who have dependable coverage and decent health care. But we can construct a kind of lifeboat alongside it for those who have been left out or dumped out, a rescue program for people like Starla Darling.

In designing this program, we'll inevitably want to build on the institutions we already have. That precept sounds as if it would severely limit our choices. But our health-care system has been a hodgepodge for so long that we actually have experience with all kinds of systems. The truth is that American health care has been more flotilla than ship. Our veterans' health-care system is a program of twelve hundred government-run hospitals and other medical facilities all across the country (just like Britain's). We could open it up to other people. We could give people a chance to join Medicare, our government insurance program (much like Canada's). Or we could provide people with coverage through the benefits program that federal workers already have, a system of private-insurance choices (like Switzerland's).

These are all established programs, each with advantages and disadvantages. The veterans' system has low costs, one of the nation's best information-technology systems for health care, and quality of care that (despite what you've heard) has, in recent years, come to exceed the private sector's on numerous measures. But it has a tightly limited choice of clinicians-you can't go to see any doctor you want, and the nearest facility may be far away from where you live. Medicare allows you to go to almost any private doctor or hospital you like, and has been enormously popular among its beneficiaries, but it costs about a third more per person and has had a hard time getting doctors and hospitals to improve the quality and safety of their care. Federal workers are entitled to a range of subsidized private-insurance choices, but insurance companies have done even less than Medicare to contain costs and most have done little to improve health care (although there are some striking exceptions).

Any of the programs could allow us to offer a starting group of Americans-the uninsured under twenty-five years of age, say-the chance to join within weeks. With time and experience, the programs could be made available to everyone who lacks coverage. The current discussion between the Obama Administration and congressional leaders seems to center on opening up the federal workers' insurance options and Medicare (or the equivalent) this way, with subsidized premiums for those with low incomes. The costs have to be dealt with. The leading proposals would try to hold down health-care spending in various ways (by, for example, requiring better management of patients with expensive chronic diseases); employers would have to pay some additional amount in taxes if they didn't provide health insurance for their employees. There's nothing easy about any of this. But, if we accept it, we'll all have a lifeboat when we need one.

It won't necessarily be clear what the final system will look like. Maybe employers will continue to slough off benefits, and that lifeboat will grow to become the entire system. Or maybe employers will decide to strengthen their benefits programs to attract employees, and American health care will emerge as a mixture of the new and the old. We could have Medicare for retirees, the V.A. for veterans, employer-organized insurance for some workers, federally organized insurance for others. The system will undoubtedly be messier than anything an idealist would devise. But the results would almost certainly be better.

Massachusetts, where I live and work, recently became the first state to adopt a system of universal health coverage for its residents. It didn't organize a government takeover of the state's hospitals or insurance companies, or force people into a new system of state-run clinics. It built on what existed. On July 1, 2007, the state began offering an online choice of four private insurance plans for people without health coverage. The cost is zero for the poor; for the rest, it is limited to no more than about eight per cent of income. The vast majority of families, who had insurance through work, didn't notice a thing when the program was launched. But those who had no coverage had to enroll in a plan or incur a tax penalty.

The results have been remarkable. After a year, 97.4 per cent of Massachusetts residents had coverage, and the remaining gap continues to close. Despite the requirement that individuals buy insurance and that employers either provide coverage or pay a tax, the program has remained extremely popular. Repeated surveys have found that at least two-thirds of the state's residents support the reform.

The Massachusetts plan didn't do anything about medical costs, however, and, with layoffs accelerating, more people require subsidized care than the state predicted. Insurance premiums continue to rise here, just as they do elsewhere in the country. Many residents also complain that eight per cent of their income is too much to pay for health insurance, even though, on average, premiums amount to twice that much. The experience has shown national policymakers that they will have to be serious about reducing costs.

For all that, the majority of state residents would not go back to the old system. I'm among them. For years, about one in ten of my patients-I specialize in cancer surgery-had no insurance. Even though I'd waive my fee, they struggled to pay for their tests, medications, and hospital stay.

I once took care of a nineteen-year-old college student who had maxed out her insurance coverage. She had a treatable but metastatic cancer. But neither she nor her parents could afford the radiation therapy that she required. I made calls to find state programs, charities-anything that could help her-to no avail. She put off the treatment for almost a year because she didn't want to force her parents to take out a second mortgage on their home. But eventually they had to choose between their daughter and their life's savings.

For the past year, I haven't had a single Massachusetts patient who has had to ask how much the necessary tests will cost; not one who has told me he needed to put off his cancer operation until he found a job that provided insurance coverage. And that's a remarkable change: a glimpse of American health care without the routine cruelty.

It will be no utopia. People will still face co-payments and premiums. There may still be agonizing disputes over coverage for non-standard treatments. Whatever the system's contours, we will still find it exasperating, even disappointing. We're not going to get perfection. But we can have transformation-which is to say, a health-care system that works. And there are ways to get there that start from where we are.

UtahOwl
Site Admin
Posts: 82
Joined: Mon Jul 28, 2008 10:48 pm

Re: How should Obama reform health care?

Post by UtahOwl »

FYI, from the NEJM Feb 2009, is a summary of money for healthcare in the recently-signed "stimulus bill":
Image

UtahOwl
Site Admin
Posts: 82
Joined: Mon Jul 28, 2008 10:48 pm

Re: How should Obama reform health care?

Post by UtahOwl »

OK, the last try at showing the Table did not work. In case this one doesn't either, here is the link - paste it into your browser!
http://content.nejm.org/cgi/content-nw/ ... 00665v1/T1
http://content.nejm.org/cgi/content-nw/ ... 00665v1/T1

UtahOwl
Site Admin
Posts: 82
Joined: Mon Jul 28, 2008 10:48 pm

Re: How should Obama reform health care?

Post by UtahOwl »

FYI, fromNEJM Feb 26,2009 - info on what was in the SCHIP reauthorization bill, and the Democratic/GOP arguments pro and con
Expanding Coverage for Children — The Democrats’ Power and SCHIP Reauthorization
John K. Iglehart
In the first demonstration of Democratic dominance on health care issues since Barack Obama captured the White House, the new Congress quickly reauthorized the State Children’s Health Insurance Program (SCHIP), enabling the president to sign the measure into law within days after taking office. Though falling short of President Obama’s goal of ensuring that “every child in America has access to affordable health care,” the measure should sustain SCHIP’s current enrollment of about 7 million and expand coverage to an additional 4.1 million children by 2013. The rapid action underscored Democrats’ intention to reverse or amend many health policies put in place during the Bush administration. Twice in 2007, Democrats failed to override vetoes of similar SCHIP bills by former President George W. Bush, who objected to their financing of the program through increased federal tobacco taxes and to their going “too far in federalizing health care.” But the newly authorized SCHIP expansion still faces a formidable hurdle. With federal and state governments seeing substantial losses in tax revenue as the recession deepens(1), many states will find it challenging to stabilize, much less expand, their current SCHIP and Medicaid enrollments, even as more people lose their jobs and their employer-sponsored health insurance.(2) A large economic stimulus package moving through Congress contains substantial relief for states, including monies to bolster SCHIP and Medicaid programs.
On January 14, eight days after the 111th Congress convened, the House approved a 4.5-year extension of SCHIP by a vote of 289 to 139. The bill attracted 40 Republican votes, reflecting some bipartisan support for expansion of public coverage for the most politically popular uninsured group, children who live in low-income families, most of which have an employed family member. On January 29, the Senate voted 66 to 32 in favor of a similar bill. Only nine Republican senators voted for the measure. Legislators quickly resolved the only issue that separated the House and Senate measures. They eliminated from the final bill a House-approved provision that would essentially have banned the future development of specialty hospitals owned or invested in by physicians who refer patients to these facilities. President Obama signed the bill into law on February 4.
SCHIP was established by the Balanced Budget Act of 1997 as a federal–state program serving children living in families with incomes at or below 200% of the federal poverty level ($35,200 for a family of three in 2008). SCHIP expanded on coverage provided by Medicaid, a far larger federal–state program covering some 60 million people (almost half of them children) with incomes below the poverty level ($17,600 for a family of three in 2008). However, states were granted the flexibility to set their own eligibility levels, and 44 states have since expanded their coverage of children (through either a newly created SCHIP or an expansion of their Medicaid programs) to those with family incomes of 200% of the federal poverty level or higher. New Jersey enrolls children with family incomes up to 350% of the poverty level — the highest threshold of any state.
SCHIP was fashioned as a bipartisan compromise, combining the Democratic preference for expanding public insurance with Republican imperatives that federal funding be capped, that states’ participation be voluntary, and that states be allowed to charge premiums and cost-sharing amounts resembling those of private coverage. States’ rapid implementation of SCHIP was attributable in part to the lure of federal matching payments more generous than Medicaid’s. In 2008, federal SCHIP payment rates to states ranged from 65 to 85% of the total costs of their programs, whereas Medicaid’s rates were 50 to 76%. Over the program’s first decade, Congress authorized the spending of $40 billion. The new law authorizes additional spending of $32.3 billion over the next 4.5 years. Along with ongoing annual federal outlays of about $5 billion, this additional amount could bring total SCHIP spending (with state matching payments) to about $57.4 billion between 2009 and 2013.
The new law enables states to enroll children with family incomes of up to 300% of the federal poverty level ($52,800 for a family of three) at the more favorable federal-payment matching rate. Coverage at higher income levels is permitted, but the matching rate reverts to the Medicaid level for states electing to enroll children above that income threshold. By a vote of 247 to 179, the House rejected a Republican amendment that would have required states to insure 90% of the children with a family income under 200% of the poverty level before allowing the enrollment of children from higher-income families. The law calls for states to phase out coverage of some 334,616 adults who are currently covered by SCHIP to make room for more low-income children. (Many of these adults are parents of eligible children; their inclusion in the program was meant to encourage them to enroll their children.) In the law’s most contentious provision, Congress allowed states — at their discretion — to restore Medicaid coverage for otherwise eligible children and pregnant women who have been in the United States legally for 5 years or less. A 1996 law had barred coverage for these groups, and considerable support had built over the years for giving states the option of reviving assistance for these previously covered persons. In provisions opposed by Republicans, the law also expands options for verifying citizenship and identity.
Republicans also opposed the manner in which SCHIP would be financed in 2009 and beyond — through a 61-cent increase in the federal excise tax on tobacco, bringing the tax for a pack of cigarettes to $1. SCHIP was largely financed through tobacco-tax revenues during its first decade. Although Democrats touted this increase as a way of achieving their “pay-as-you-go” pledge, they also argued that it would reduce children’s exposure to secondhand smoke and discourage young people from taking up smoking. Republicans called the increased cigarette levy regressive, asserting that it amounted to a tax on the poor.

Benefits mandated by the SCHIP law are similar to those covered through the standard Blue Cross–Blue Shield plan that many federal employees select or through a package offered to employees of a private company that contracts with a health maintenance organization. However, benefits are less generous than those of Medicaid programs. Under the new SCHIP law, dental services were added as a required benefit in response to mounting evidence that low-income children have very poor access to oral health services. Although quality of care has been a focus in Medicaid managed care for some time and all states use some form of quality measurement when purchasing insurance products for SCHIPcovered children, there has been no formal policy on the quality of children’s health care under Medicaid and SCHIP. A study of the quality of ambulatory care delivered to a random national sample of children showed that children receive indicated care about 46.5% of the time(3), as compared with 55% for adult care.(4) Having been urged for a decade to devote more attention to improving the quality of children’s care(5), Congress established extensive new requirements for the Department of Health and Human Services (DHHS). With authorized resources of $225 million over 5 years, the new quality provisions represent “the single largest explicit federal investment in pediatric quality to date,” according to Lisa Simpson of Cincinnati Children’s Hospital Medical Center.
Congress directed the DHHS to develop new measures of both the quality of pediatric care and the success of Medicaid and SCHIP in meeting children’s needs. The law stipulates that the measures should be developed with extensive input from pediatric and quality experts and that the DHHS should provide comprehensive information regarding the delivery and outcomes of care, identify disparities in care, improve existing measures of children’s health and update them periodically, and report to Congress on the degree to which states are using the measures. The law also includes funding for demonstration projects to improve the delivery of children’s health care, address childhood obesity, and promote the use of health information technology. Although many states and the Robert Wood Johnson Foundation have invested substantial sums in reaching out to enroll eligible children in SCHIP, an estimated 5 million to 6 million such children remain without coverage. The law therefore offers bonus payments to states that increase their enrollments by a certain amount, makes it easier for states to implement “express lane” eligibility mechanisms, and provides for grants to local governments and community-based organizations for conducting outreach campaigns, especially in rural areas and underserved populations.
The rapidity with which Democrats managed to reauthorize SCHIP should not be taken as a sign that it will be easy to pass broader proposals for expanding coverage to other uninsured populations. Democrats saw the SCHIP measure as unfinished business from the 110th Congress. Moving on to more ambitious reforms will be more difficult, given the rapidly increasing federal deficit, the competing claims for federal resources, and the determination of Republicans to forestall the growth of public insurance. Nevertheless, President Obama believes that a major health care initiative must be “intimately woven into our overall economic recovery plan.” As he has said, health care reform is “not something that we can put off because we are in an emergency. This is part of the emergency.”
No potential conflict of interest relevant to this article was reported. This article (10.1056/NEJMp0900461) was published at NEJM.org on February 4, 2009.
Mr. Iglehart is a national correspondent for the Journal.

1.Sack K, Zezima K. Growing need for Medicaid strains states. New York Times. January
22, 2009:A1.
2. Boyd DJ, Dadayan L. State revenue report: state tax revenue falling sharply in fourth
quarter, early data show: sales taxes, income taxes both show decline; further losses appear likely in first half of 2009. No. 74. Albany, NY: Nelson A. Rockefeller Institute of Government, 2008.
3. Mangione-Smith R, DeCristofaro AH, Setodji CM, et al. The quality of ambulatory care delivered to children in the United States. N Engl J Med 2007;357:1515-23.
4. McGlynn EA, Asch SM, Adams J, et al. The quality of health care delivered to adults
in the United States. N Engl J Med 2003; 348:2635-45.
5. Simpson L, Fairbrother G, Hale S, Homer C. Reauthorizing SCHIP: opportunities for promoting effective health coverage and high-quality care for children and adolescents. New York: The Commonwealth Fund, 2007. (Accessed February 5, 2009, at http:// http://www.commonwealthfund.org/publica ... _id=514972.)
Copyright © 2009 Massachusetts Medical Society.

Post Reply

Return to “Original Proposal - How Should Pres. Obama Reform Health Care - March 11”

Who is online

Users browsing this forum: No registered users and 1 guest